Show Posts

This section allows you to view all posts made by this member. Note that you can only see posts made in areas you currently have access to.


Messages - More Than Mortal

Pages: 1 ... 169170171 172173 ... 502
5101
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:46:06 PM »
i will say that the bulk of these people are indeed authorities
Ah, yes!

Fornicate the establishment, right?

5102
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:45:32 PM »
Then you went to college and started hanging out with chavs and became a conservative.
Wait, were the chavs conservatives who then convinced me? Or did having to spend time with chavs turn me into a conservative?

5103
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:44:37 PM »
but for starters stuff about the development of your current knowledge base
Reading a lot of Wikipedia articles to get a foundation, and then reading a lot of books to develop that.

Quote
what political and existential things you might find arbitrary and unnecessary
I don't really understand the question.

Quote
if you're familiar with non-Aristotelian semantics
If I understand it right, I'm not a fan of null-A logic.

Quote
where you think this race is going socially with advancing technology, etc.[/color]
Incredible economic prosperity as technology means we no longer need to work, and probably self-cannibalisation as society can't handle the lack of need for employment.

5104
The Flood / Re: Immigration is a scourge on society
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:41:36 PM »
Explain, then.
I'm joking, you fuck.

I'm incredibly pro-immigration.

5106
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:35:45 PM »

You ever thought about murdering a person?

And, have you ever seriously thought about hurting a person?

5107
The Flood / Re: Describe the Poster Above You With a Picture or Gif
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:32:32 PM »

5108
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:31:19 PM »
I don't know why peyote are saying Meta, every time I learn something new about him I cringe.
You used to be cool, man.

5109
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:29:04 PM »
Meta
What do you want to know?

5110
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:28:35 PM »
i mean, i'm extremely open, so

if anyone ever wanted know damn near anything about me, they could just ask
You ever thought about something while wanking so disgusting you then felt guilty afterwards?

5111
The Flood / Re: That Sep7 User You Want to Know More About
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:25:37 PM »
Why are people saying Verb?

The guy's an open fucking book.

5112
slash is "kill yourself"
Well how about that.

5113
The Flood / Immigration is a scourge on society
« on: June 08, 2015, 04:22:21 PM »
















lol











no but seriously

5114
Well besides maybe slash. He didn't exactly go into detail with his opinion.
Slash is here?

5115
The Flood / Re: That awkward moment when you drive to work
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:31:30 PM »
bc gettin shrekt

5116
The Flood / Re: I'm voting BNP
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:27:11 PM »
Good.

England will look like a bowl of fucking coco pops before long, if we don't do something about it.

5117
The Flood / Re: How do you pronounce meta?
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:20:55 PM »
i've heard some people say it like MAY-duh

i wanna punch them
lol

pretty certain the only greek letter you pronounce that way is beta

5118
The Flood / Re: That awkward moment when you drive to work
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:20:15 PM »
Must've been embarrassing stood by your 1997 Ford Fiesta.

5119
The Flood / Re: How do you pronounce meta?
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:19:30 PM »
Meh-tah.

5120
2. Work is work, Meta. When you have no days off in a week, and you're on your feet every day, you can't call that not productive. Snare in that statement.
Productivity isn't defined by how much you work, it's defined by your marginal product. Would people working fourteen hour shifts, seven days a week, digging holes with spoons be productive? No, of course they wouldn't.

Quote
The fuck is somebody working off a bare minimum going to do to buy a home or property when they can't even afford it because the guy up top can basically take the cake and eat it too?
I'm fairly certain the dude has to buy the property off the people who live their, provided they actually own it. Even in cases where the government exercises eminent domain and expropriates the land, the owners still need to be provided with compensation.

5121
Making it illegal is a deterrent so people don't fall victim to its addictive properties.
Not really, even the Home Office acknowledges that there's little correlation between drug use and enforcement methods.

Not to mention, illegalising the drug does three very damaging things. First, it puts people who nevertheless fall pray to addiction in a holding pen with other criminals. Secondly, it incentivises drug dealers to downgrade the purity of the drug, adding dangerous adulterants or even supply different drugs altogether which aren't illegal yet still dangerous. And finally, it pads the pockets of the cartels by increasing their cost of doing business.

5122
Serious / Here's What's Causing Inequality
« on: June 08, 2015, 02:05:08 PM »
Scott Sumner over at the National Review.
Quote
Why are wealth and income inequality increasing? Why is labor, relative to capital, commanding a declining share of national income? These have become the central questions in the economics profession, and they’re increasingly central to our political debates as well. Much of the discussion seems to suggest that there is some sort of mystery to be explained. Perhaps corporations are getting better at lobbying in Washington. Or maybe there has been a cultural change that makes CEOs bolder in demanding high pay.

We find those sorts of explanations to be unsatisfactory. Once we consider recent structural changes in the economy, there may not be much left to explain. Here are three key factors: first, obstacles to building and subsidies to homeowners, which raise rents in residential real estate; second, the increasing complexity of regulation, which imposes burdens on smaller firms and discourages new entry; and third, the growing importance of intellectual property.

In all three cases, government regulation has probably contributed to inequality.

Why Are Housing Rents So High?

Until recently, economists tended to assume that the labor share of national income in the U.S. was fairly stable, as labor had earned about 50 to 59 percent of GDP since the Bureau of Economic Analysis began tracking the data in 1929. Given that the economy has grown by nearly 500 percent over that time (in real terms, per capita), most economists thought that long-run economic growth was far more important than distributional issues. In the last few decades, however, the labor share has dropped modestly, while the share of national income going to capital has increased.

Last year a French economist named Thomas Piketty created a sensation in the world of economics with a major historical study of capital and wealth inequality. Piketty argued that the recent slowdown in economic growth was likely to lead to even greater concentrations of wealth at the very top. More recently, an MIT graduate student named Matthew Rognlie took a closer look at Piketty’s data and found that almost the entire change in the share of domestic income going to capital in major developed economies was explained by rising rents on residential real estate. Non-rental capital income (including the corporate sector) still has a fairly stable share of domestic income.

To understand Rognlie’s argument, it is important to distinguish between the consumption of housing and the ownership of housing. Both tenants and owners consume housing in the same way, but only one pays a rent check that can easily be counted toward statistics such as the national income. To address this problem, the government estimates the “implicit rent” on owner-occupied housing by looking at rental equivalents — the rent on comparable properties.

In terms of labor vs. capital income in the U.S., in the eight years leading to the fourth quarter of 2014, compensation declined from 53.7 percent to 52.4 percent of Gross Domestic Income — a significant decline, considering the tight range of this measure over time. But rents moved relentlessly higher during this period, and as a result, rental income to homeowners climbed from 1.3 percent to 3.7 percent of GDI. If we add homeowners’ implicit rental income to compensation, then the combined share has actually grown by 1.1 percent instead of falling by 1.3 percent over this period.

Interest rates are now quite low, even in real terms, and one would expect the combination of high rents and low interest rates to lead to an enormous boom in housing construction. However, since 2006, the construction of new homes has plummeted to historically low levels. What explains this discrepancy?

It’s not enough to point to the severe recession, as that would have been expected to depress construction by depressing rents. As can be seen in the following graph, renters have seen a rising share of their incomes going to rent. The rent/income ratio briefly leveled off during the housing boom, but has jumped during the bust because of the shortage of new housing. Housing may have been overbuilt in some locations, but nationwide a growing scarcity of housing has hit renters hard.

We see two important regulatory factors in high rents. One that has been of increasing importance in recent decades is restrictive zoning. Today it is much harder to get approval for large new housing developments in many of the coastal states — where one can still observe quite elevated house prices in addition to high rents — partly for environmental reasons and partly due to “NIMBYism.” Many environmentalists favor “smart growth,” such as more high-density development along transit lines in bigger cities. But those developments are often blocked by regulations such as rules requiring parking spaces for each housing unit. Many economists on both the left and the right have become highly critical of these restrictions on new-home construction.

The second factor is that it became much harder to get a mortgage in the U.S. after 2006. This is partly due to the large losses that banks and homeowners suffered during the subprime crisis, but it’s also because regulation has been tightened. Those unable to buy new single-family homes because of a lack of new construction were pushed into the rental market, driving rents higher despite the relatively weak economy. Because renters tend to be less wealthy than homeowners on average, this worsens economic inequality.

Our owner-biased tax code already puts renters at a disadvantage, relative to homeowners, because the rent they pay must cover all the income and capital-gains taxes that landlords pay but homeowners do not. Rent inflation from the limits to homebuilding that we have described further worsens economic inequality, because homeowners tend to have higher incomes than renters, spend less of their income on housing, and are immune to rent increases because they own their homes.

The housing bust, made worse by regressive zoning and tax laws, is creating haves and have-nots — owners and renters.

The Regulatory Burden on Small Firms

The combined forces of globalization and the telecommunications revolution have led to substantial growth in the size of many high-tech firms. Some of this shift is inevitable, and indeed beneficial to the U.S.; the U.S. is better off than it would be if the high-skill jobs created at Apple, Google, and Microsoft had instead been created overseas. But it does increase inequality. In a 2015 NBER working paper, Holger M. Mueller, Paige P. Ouimet, and Elena Simintzi find evidence that wage differentials and skill premiums increase with firm size.

Read more at: http://www.nationalreview.com/article/419442/heres-whats-driving-inequality-scott-sumner-kevin-erdmann The combined forces of globalization and the telecommunications revolution have led to substantial growth in the size of many high-tech firms. Some of this shift is inevitable, and indeed beneficial to the U.S.; the U.S. is better off than it would be if the high-skill jobs created at Apple, Google, and Microsoft had instead been created overseas. But it does increase inequality. In a 2015 NBER working paper, Holger M. Mueller, Paige P. Ouimet, and Elena Simintzi find evidence that wage differentials and skill premiums increase with firm size.

Unfortunately, many government regulations tend to favor larger firms. In recent years we have seen the passage of some extremely complex regulations involving thousands of pages of rules, such as Sarbanes-Oxley, Dodd-Frank, and the Affordable Care Act. The Food and Drug Administration, the Department of Defense, and the public health-care complex tend to create opportunities for uber-firms within industries, which act as clearinghouses for public contracts and regulatory demands.

Many of the new regulations may end up being counterproductive by limiting new entry. The most powerful regulatory force in the world is the threat of new competition. The Richmond Fed notes that from 2011 to 2013, only four new banks were established in the U.S., while historically there have generally been more than 100 per year. They attribute this to low bank profits and more regulatory-compliance demands since the crisis, especially a new 2009 FDIC rule that creates substantial new regulatory burdens aimed specifically at new banks.

In other industries, the well-publicized expansion of occupational licensing, ever-widening labor regulations, and petty local regulatory burdens limits the movement between wage earner and proprietor that once served as a natural safety net for the unemployed, a source of wage competition, and a breeding ground for smaller firms.

While some regulations may be desirable, and even necessary, the recognition that complex regulations benefit large firms, leading to increased inequality, seems oddly absent from much political discourse.

Intellectual Property and Inequality

We’ve already seen that the share of national income going to capital has been fairly stable, if you exclude rental income. But this glosses over some interesting changes within the corporate world. A 2014 NBER study by Erling Barth, Alex Bryson, James C. Davis, and Richard B. Freeman found that in addition to the increased inequality in incomes that comes from larger firm size, there has also been a trend of more variance in returns between firms. It seems plausible that this reflects the increasingly “winner take all” nature of 21st-century capitalism. Peter Thiel’s popular book Zero to One captures the spirit of this trend, with its suggestion that new start-up firms aim for a monopoly position.

It’s hard to say how much of this is due to intellectual-property rights such as patents, copyrights, and trademarks. A study that has recently received a lot of attention shows a huge rise in the share of corporate capital that is “intangible,” from about one-sixth in 1975 to five-sixths today. (Apple, for instance, has a market value of $740 billion but net tangible assets of only $100 billion.) As Robin Hanson recently pointed out, this raises the question of why investors could not compete with a company by replicating all its tangible assets at one-sixth the cost.

Of course, we need to be careful here, as there are many complex accounting issues that may affect these estimates. In addition, the term “intangible” need not imply “protected by intellectual property rights.” Companies such as eBay and Facebook probably benefit from “network effects” – people like to use these services because lots of other people also use them. We have seen a pattern of serial monopolies, where tech firms establish dominance but quickly lose it. Many of the firms that appeared as headline-grabbing IPOs over the past 20 years are already forgotten. Getting intellectual property rights is now more important and more difficult than it was when dominant firms were defined by physical capital.

Many of the newer industries also feature very low marginal costs of production. Large investments are made in areas like software and biotech, with many firms falling by the wayside while the successful firms can earn large profit margins. Producing the first unit of, say, a computer program is extremely expensive, but after that, manufacturing costs may fall close to zero. This winner-take-all feature of modern market economies dramatically increases inequality among capitalists.

There are good arguments for some intellectual-property protection, which can spur innovation. And yet many economists on both the left and the right have argued that the protections have gone too far, into areas with no obvious social benefits. Copyright protections once lasted for 14 years, applied only to maps and books, and could be renewed once if the author was still alive. Now they’ve been extended to many other products, extend for 50 years after the death of the author, and last for at least 95 years for corporations. These extensions are widely seen as reflecting the lobbying power of companies such as Disney. In the high-tech sector, patents are often granted for seemingly minor and obvious innovations. President Obama has recently been pressing the Asian countries to enact stricter intellectual-property protections. This may be in America’s self-interest, but transferring money from Asian consumers to Disney shareholders almost certainly worsens global inequality.

How Capitalism Is Supposed to Work

The market economy should have natural mechanisms to limit inequality. If housing is very expensive in coastal California, more firms should build houses. If Mickey Mouse toys and Barbie dolls are profitable, more companies should produce those toys. If some professions make more than others, people should move into the higher-paying professions.

We certainly don’t wish to suggest that regulation is the only factor increasing inequality, but to the extent that zoning rules, limits on mortgage lending, occupational licensing restrictions, and intellectual-property rights limit new competition, we should not be surprised if increased inequality is one of the side effects.

Definitely worth the read, but it's a long piece so here are the take-aways:

Housing rents:
- In the last few decades, however, the labor share has dropped modestly, while the share of national income going to capital has increased.

- an MIT graduate student named Matthew Rognlie took a closer look at Piketty’s data and found that almost the entire change in the share of domestic income going to capital in major developed economies was explained by rising rents on residential real estate. Non-rental capital income (including the corporate sector) still has a fairly stable share of domestic income.

- renters have seen a rising share of their incomes going to rent.

- One that has been of increasing importance in recent decades is restrictive zoning.

- The second factor is that it became much harder to get a mortgage in the U.S. after 2006.

- Because renters tend to be less wealthy than homeowners on average, this worsens economic inequality.

Regulatory Burden:
- Unfortunately, many government regulations tend to favor larger firms. In recent years we have seen the passage of some extremely complex regulations involving thousands of pages of rules, such as Sarbanes-Oxley, Dodd-Frank, and the Affordable Care Act.

- Many of the new regulations may end up being counterproductive by limiting new entry.

- The Richmond Fed notes that from 2011 to 2013, only four new banks were established in the U.S., while historically there have generally been more than 100 per year.

-In other industries, the well-publicized expansion of occupational licensing, ever-widening labor regulations, and petty local regulatory burdens limits the movement between wage earner and proprietor that once served as a natural safety net for the unemployed, a source of wage competition, and a breeding ground for smaller firms.

Intellectual Property:
- It’s hard to say how much of this is due to intellectual-property rights such as patents, copyrights, and trademarks. A study that has recently received a lot of attention shows a huge rise in the share of corporate capital that is “intangible,” from about one-sixth in 1975 to five-sixths today. (Apple, for instance, has a market value of $740 billion but net tangible assets of only $100 billion.)

- Producing the first unit of, say, a computer program is extremely expensive, but after that, manufacturing costs may fall close to zero. This winner-take-all feature of modern market economies dramatically increases inequality among capitalists.

-Copyright protections once lasted for 14 years, applied only to maps and books, and could be renewed once if the author was still alive. Now they’ve been extended to many other products, extend for 50 years after the death of the author, and last for at least 95 years for corporations.

5123
The current system is engineered for the selfish. You can't deny that because you said it yourself.
There's a big difference between being selfish and then being incentivised to produce things.

Quote
The system does not support that. Doesn't support the lower end of the spectrum. For example. The farmers, up here. These people work their asses off. And, sure, maybe they don't have the heads to go higher places. So they do the best they can.
Working your ass off doesn't make you productive; if Canadian agriculture is being unproductive it should be allowed to die off, so labour can re-allocate itself. That said, like most countries, Canada also has farm subsidies which keep the inefficiency of the sector alive.

But they're getting rammed up the ass and they can't do anything about it.

Quote
but does not fuck the lower end so hard?
Guaranteed minimum income for people earning nothing, and wage subsidies for people earning below a certain level. While abolishing the minimum wage.

5124
How would you do it?
How would I stop costs from going up?

5125
What kind of benifits would you pick? Let's do some thinking.
Private or state benefits?

I wouldn't pick any regardless, I don't think. Those benefits are still a cost which wouldn't otherwise be there if there were no ceiling, and people who've reached the ceiling are surely wealthy enough to cover their expenses without needing any kind of benefit.

5126
i think there's a lot more people like that than you think though
That may be so, but productivity in the labour market doesn't just come from the supply-side. Say you have an executive who's reached the wage ceiling, and he really wants to be Treasury Secretary. But this guy just doesn't get fiscal policy, he's incredibly unproductive at implementing policies around tax and spending.

Let's say he has a PhD in monetary economics, and would make a great central banker. The wages for all three jobs are at the ceiling, so he's essentially got a free choice. But no matter how much prosperity he would secure at the Federal Reserve he still goes for Treasury Secretary because that's his passion, because the Fed has no carrots with which to lure him in to become chairman.

Nevertheless, I'm not even sure why you'd want this policy anyway unless it's out of some spiteful feelings towards the wealthy. Implementing what is essentially a 100pc tax rate on earnings over the ceiling is only going to expropriate savings, which makes everybody poorer.

5127
>no incentive to advance or innovate

obviously you mean personal incentives, but i mean, that's just kind of hilarious
Ahem:

Quote
Sure, you get passionate people who will do it anyway

5128
The Flood / Re: How do you pronounce combatant?
« on: June 08, 2015, 01:20:43 PM »
obviously
>americlaps

get out of here with that fucking linguistic imperialism

i know how iraq turned out!

5129
No matter the pay.
But there's no incentive to advance or innovate as soon as you hit that ceiling. Sure, you get passionate people who will do it anyway, but most of us need some kind of carrot to get the ball rolling.

5130
Doesn't quite fit. How would you see an under supply of labor? Or, more important. Why?
Because nobody is going to work in higher positions for no extra pay, provided they'd hit the cap.

Are you talking about just wage labour, or things like capital income too?

Pages: 1 ... 169170171 172173 ... 502